Regulation or innovation?

Chris Gilchrist

Robert Shiller, one of the world’s most influential economists, used an op-ed column in the FT last year to argue for more financial innovation. He claimed it wasn’t innovation (as in slice-and-dice mortgage-backed securities, etc, aka toxic assets) that caused the sub-prime crisis and the credit crunch, but lack of it. Shiller said we need more financial innovation so that we can have things like mortgages that include insurance against falling house prices and redundancy.

I fear that the learned prof, like many residents of Financeland, has spent too much time away from mundane surreality (this is where people know everything about I’m a celebrity contestants but don’t know what they’ll live on in retirement).

Shiller argued that we don’t have a problem with complicated gadgets even though we don’t have a clue how they work. True, but that’s because we don’t need to: we know whether they work or not, and that’s all we need. With complex financial products, though, we don’t know whether they work or not. Not only that, the people who make them often don’t know, and nor do the regulators. In fact it’s even worse, because it’s in the nature of financial markets that there’s no way anyone can know whether some complex products will work or not. Take structured products, where the best you can say about any possible outcome is “probably”.

This is where Shiller goes wrong, and the regulators too. Would you buy a mobile phone that “probably” works in Europe, or a TV that “may work” in HD? Of course not. Shiller argues, I think correctly, that most people are overly cautious with finance because they don’t understand. One reason is that we know that gadgets are governed by the laws of physics. But what are the laws governing financial gadgets? Until recently, many of the profs would have said that finance theory provided those laws. You wouldn’t want to have to argue that in court today.

Financial products are different from things. They are mainly promises, and if those promises are broken or are too weaselly phrased, people won’t buy. It’s true that financial markets are unpredictable, but it is possible to limit the unpredictability. It’s in the public interest to do so, because we’re very poor at probabilistic reasoning. That means that if there’s a wide range of possible outcomes, we’ll tend to view the proposition as more risky than it is based on the actual distribution of outcomes – so we’ll consistently err in our financial decisions. You’re not going to change hard-wired biases in human reasoning like this with a smidgeon of money education in schools. The best regulators can do is create a framework for products with a narrower range of outcomes that we can assess with our limited reasoning capacities.

Is that possible? Of course. Regulators initially did a good job in setting rules that governed occupational final salary pensions and with-profits life assurance. Those were apparently simple products, underneath which lay a lot of complexity. Regulators didn’t stay up to speed with the complexity, so they didn’t prevent abuses of the rules, hence the terminal decline in both products.

Shiller argued that given freedom, firms will use financial engineering, derivatives etc to create better products.  The evidence isn’t in favour. But history shows that prescriptive product regulation can enable the creation of products Joe Soap can understand, buy and benefit from. That’s a positive approach to financial complexity and innovation which delivers a public benefit. 

Of course, there is an alternative: finance theory’s freedom mantra. “Anything goes”, including toxic stuff like precipice bonds, provided you’ve ticked the FSA’s process boxes. A system that regulates everything about financial products -except the products. Welcome to blunderland.

Chris Gilchrist is director of Churchill Investments

Newsletter

News and expert analysis straight to your inbox

Sign up

Comments

There are 2 comments at the moment, we would love to hear your opinion too.

  1. There is a continual talk about regulating products.

    The regulators are charged with protecting non- professional investors.
    Product innovation should be allowed as the industry could decay.

    Would it be better to regulate the correct identification of an investors need.
    This could be satisfied any product which meets the need provided it is better than any Government sponsored investment. Government is defined as any Government in the EC. This to apply to all salesmen and advisers.
    It would still allow product innovation. Indeed, it would provide a framework for it by focusing on the customer.

  2. Even more worrying is the regulator’s predilection towards ‘anything is better than nothing’ whereas in fact it should be thinking about the efficacy in ‘nothing is better than anything’.

    We need regulatory balance, I see none.

Leave a comment